Reinventing Welfare Regimes
Employers and the Implementation of Active Social Policy
Cathie Jo Martin *
Introduction
Throughout Europe a revolution is transforming the welfare state. Inspired by EU leadership, nations from Sweden to Spain are seeking to make the welfare state more "active" in order to rescue those on the dole from the social isolation that comes from years and even generations of unemployment and poverty. Employers, viewed as frontline warriors in this battle against unemployment, are pressed into service by governments eager to bring new economic relevance to the types of jobs and training programs that have often had a make-work quality in the past.
Many view this shift in social provision as simultaneously representing radical change within welfare regimes and an impressive amount of formal conceptual convergence among regime types. Radical transformation has occurred to the extent that new reforms are changing the essential goals of social provision: the aim of "employability" for all individuals may be replacing the older goal of full employment (with the marginally employed relegated to safety-net programs).1 At least conceptually, these reforms also seem to represent an impressive amount of policy convergence in that they borrow from various regimes, thus bringing countries to create new policy forms that break with their historical approaches to social provision.2 [End Page 39]
Given this conceptual congruence, the most significant differences among the various national welfare reform efforts may well be at the point of implementation; this variation poses intriguing puzzles for scholars. For example, while the British and Danish social plans are similar on paper, they have inspired very different take-up rates among employers. Danish employers have had virtually no prior involvement in implementing social programs, yet they have participated in far greater numbers in the programmatic delivery of services than their British counterparts, who, by contrast, have traditionally played a substantial role in providing private employment-based social benefits. While Scandinavian employers have historically supported the welfare state more than managers in liberal countries, Danish firms' current involvement in programmatic service delivery nonetheless represents a fundamental break with the past.3
This article's central empirical objective is to evaluate why firms participate in the new active programs and, thereby, to account for why Danish employers have participated at higher rates than their British counterparts. The empirical analysis draws from interviews with 107 randomly selected British and Danish corporations, from which we can isolate the causal variables that bring firms both to participate in active labor-market and social programs and to explore business attitudes toward the newest generation of welfare reform.
More broadly, this article uses the case of active labor-market and social policy to explain the perpetuation of welfare regime trajectories at moments when social policy forms appear to be both digressing from their regime traditions and converging across countries. Because the most significant divergence among plans seems to appear at the point of implementation, this article examines whether the processes of operationalizing and implementing the concept of active social reforms contribute to the perpetuation of regime trajectories. My hypothesis is that even at moments of policy convergence, regime distinctions should persist in the subtleties of programmatic design and in employers' expectations about state administrative capacities that result from cumulative experiences with past policies. These legacies, embedded in regimes, should have important feedback effects on employers' participation in the programs and influence both firms' reasons for joining the effort and the comparative take-up rates. [End Page 40]
The programmatic designs of Danish and British active labor-market plans have diverged in a manner predicted by differences in their regimes. In keeping with social democratic traditions, the Danish plans cover a more universal population, link the programs to broader training efforts, and arguably contribute to a major collective goal—an encompassing labor market. Befitting a liberal welfare state, the British plans target a more narrow population, do little to expand skills, and continue in the punitive track of former Prime Minister Thatcher's social interventions.4
These programmatic differences have had profound feedback effects on firms' willingness to participate in these programs; indeed, Danish firms participated more than their British counterparts precisely because of the social democratic tint to welfare reform. While 68 percent of Danish employers participated in the active labor-market and social programs, only 40 percent of British firms did so (many of which ultimately reneged on their promise to create jobs for the unemployed). The interviews reveal that Danish employers viewed program constituents less negatively, anticipated greater material benefit from participating, and evaluated the programs' administration more highly than did British firms. While Danish firms participated in order to gain access to a more highly skilled labor supply, British companies joined the effort largely for political reasons (to appease the new government) or to gain access to cheap labor.
Regression analyses, by demonstrating that different causal variables significantly influenced the likelihood of participation in the two countries, further support the theory that British and Danish companies participated for divergent reasons. The British firms most likely to participate were large, had a high percentage of sales to the public sector (in short, they were vulnerable to political pressures from the government), and had many unskilled blue-collar workers (thus, they could benefit from an influx of cheap labor). By contrast, the Danish firms most likely to participate were smaller and had blue-collar workers at all skills levels (thus, these firms were well suited to benefit from the training offered by the programs).
This article aims to contribute to our understanding of how differences in implementation contribute to regime perpetuation and cross-national diversity, an understudied area in welfare state theory that is of growing salience in this era of private sector solutions in which employers' [End Page 41] and in implementation is critical to policy success. Regime theory has provided important analytic constructs with which to ponder how policy legacies shape new legislative initiatives and macrotrends in social spending.5 Scholars have shown how regime-driven policy legacies alter the programmatic realization of conceptually similar social reforms across countries and influence the politics of retrenchment.6 These analytic tools, however, have not been utilized to explain cross-national differences in the implementation of social programs. My aim is to demonstrate that the policy feedback effects that shape national trajectories in welfare state spending also influence employers' implementation of social programs.
In an age of neoliberalism, questions about regime perpetuation have profound implications for the fate of social democracy. The Danish experiment, at heart, is an effort to locate a new equilibrium between growth and equity appropriate in the postindustrial economy. The falling productivity growth rates that have accompanied deindustrialization have created a "trilemma" for nations seeking simultaneously to achieve wage equity, to realize full employment, and to maintain their fiscal solvency.7 In asking firms to reemploy the socially excluded, Danish policy entrepreneurs hope to solve the trilemma of the postindustrial economy and to fix the decommodification traps of the Scandinavian welfare state. These bureaucrats would match unemployed persons' skills levels to employers' job requirements and would subsidize (by up to 50 percent) firms' employment of disabled workers to perform unproductive tasks within the companies. These "win-win" arrangements would expand employment, reduce government social expenditures (by getting people off the welfare rolls), allow companies to fill (with low-wage workers) unproductive positions that were sacrificed in the push for global competition, and maintain wage equality (because the new low-wage positions are subsidized by the state).
The ultimate success of the Scandinavian model depends on the state's ability to build pro-social-policy coalitions of broad majorities; in effect, they need to construct a new labor-management accord. This article provides an intimate picture of this process of consensus building in the Scandinavian welfare state. In the case of active labor-market [End Page 42] policy (ALMP), Danish employers have expectations about the legitimate scope of government that their British peers do not share. Their social democratic government (in substantial agreement with the other parties) has demonstrated powerful leadership in shaping employers' interests in the social policy area; these efforts have been successful in great part due to the pragmatism and efficacy of the Danish welfare state. These embedded policy legacies may keep the Scandinavian model alive, creating continuities in the implementation processes and structuring patterns of business/government relations, even at moments when neoliberal sentiments are changing the policy tools and location of service delivery.
Employers and Active Labor-Market Policy
New risks that have challenged contemporary welfare states have initiated this process of social policy transformation. Globalization and structural unemployment may have created pressures for welfare states to retrench or at least to cap social spending increases.8 The falling productivity growth rates that have accompanied deindustrialization have created a trilemma for nations seeking simultaneously to achieve wage equity, to realize full employment, and to maintain their fiscal solvency. Different solutions to the welfare trilemma have different implications for the future of inequality, growth, and social justice.9 Demographic and family-structure changes have shrunk the worker/dependent ratio, added to concerns about budget deficits, altered the caregiving structure, and increased the need for working-age individuals to contribute to the labor force. The existing structures of the welfare state put into place during the Golden Age may be ill equipped to handle the challenges of the postindustrial era.10
These emergent risks have inspired new conceptions of the welfare state, most prominently, active labor-market and social policies designed to reintegrate the long-term unemployed back into the core economy, to relieve budgetary pressures on social spending, and to end social exclusion. With rules about the duration of benefits ("sticks") and [End Page 43] access to training or to subsidized jobs ("carrots"), these policies seek to redirect attention toward the socially excluded and toward skills development.11 While Fordist-era social plans met the initial training needs of the core labor force and channeled other individuals into safety-net programs, the new policies emphasize the importance of renewed skills development in meeting the challenges of rapidly changing technology in the postindustrial economy.12 ALMP programs have been described as "realignments" rather than as "path dependencies" in scaling back social rights as well as in shifting the goals of social intervention from income maintenance to employment promotion, from full employment to individual employability, and from a state guarantee of income to a commitment to invest in social capital.13 These policies typically involve employers more so than did prior interventions, both because big, universal state programs are more difficult to fund and because private sector training and subsidized jobs are considered more likely to lead to permanent employment than are public options.14
Since the November 1997 Luxembourg Employment Summit, the European Union has pushed this active model, which has resulted in substantial similarity among national plans.15 Yet cross-national variation becomes apparent at the point of implementation, which suggests that this somewhat-neglected aspect of welfare state studies is increasingly responsible for such differences.16 For instance, Denmark outspends Britain on active labor-market policies and more successfully obtains its employers' participation in the programs.17 These comparative [End Page 44] spending figures may not surprise us, given Denmark's historic leadership in public spending on all labor-market measures. Yet given their virtual lack of involvement in previous social programs, it seems paradoxical that Danish employers would suddenly take this lead in implementing active labor-market measures. Granted, the employer-provided benefits still represent only a small portion of the overall social reforms and Danish employers historically have politically supported social policy to a greater extent than British firms. Nonetheless, the use of Danish employers to implement active social programs—a core component of active social policy—diverges profoundly from that nation's tradition of governmental solutions to social problems.18 Denmark's initiative in the move away from decommodification is also surprising and has caused critics to fear an attack on the rights of citizenship; nonetheless, the Danish lead in social intervention remains unchallenged, even in this pan-European move to a liberal reform.19
Several possibilities might explain these puzzling developments. First, Danish firms may have economic structural characteristics that make their participation in the social programs more tolerable (or even beneficial) than it is for their British counterparts. Although managers generally resist regulations, companies still may support policies that carry special benefit for them, such as policies that either improve their market position vis-à-vis their competitors or appease their workers.20 In an analysis of employers' preferences, we might anticipate that the same structural characteristics would shape firms' preferences in the two countries, and in accounting for the cross-national divergence, we might anticipate that Denmark has a greater number of firms with the salient structural characteristics than does Britain.
Scholarly literature identifies eight economic characteristics that may influence a company's preferences for social policies (see Table 1). A firm's size might be directly proportional to its participation in social programs because larger firms are more likely to have preexisting training programs or to have economies of scale in political action.21 Firms with lower profits (as a percentage of total sales) might be more likely to participate in order to obtain access to cheap labor (although it is [End Page 45]
![]() Click for larger view |
Table 1
Hypotheses |
also possible that more profitable firms could more easily devote resources to social initiatives). Firms with higher percentages of exports might participate in order to gain a source of cheap labor. The presence of unions within a firm might compel its management to take more socially responsible positions, although unions might also view these programs as threatening to more standard employment.22 Firms with a greater percentage of public sector sales may be more likely to support government policies, either to curry favor or to control their environment.23 Companies with a higher percentage of unskilled blue-collar [End Page 46] workers (or their unskilled, service sector worker equivalents) might participate more in order to gain cheap labor. Firms with a higher percentage of blue-collar workers at all skills levels—that is, not white-collar workers—might participate in order to secure higher skills for their workforce.24 The terms "unskilled" and "skilled" workers designate both manufacturing and service sector equivalents. Firms with lower average wages might participate to gain cheap labor.
Theories of corporate preference that rely upon individual firms' characteristics suffer in that they fail to take into account institutional differences across settings. In particular, they neglect the differences in public policy regimes and their divergent impacts on employers' incentives to engage in the new social reforms.
Thus, a second explanation for the cross-national variations in employer take-up rates of the new programs (and my core theoretical argument) is that the Danish and British policies create different incentives for employers to participate, or have different "feedback effects." This argument draws from two somewhat separate theoretical traditions; taken together, they imply that the essential qualities of regimes embedded in programmatic design have feedback effects on employers' willingness to help implement social programs.
Comparative welfare regime theorists study how policy legacies shape new social reforms. Each of the three (or four) welfare regime types embraces a characteristic set of policy tools, beneficiaries, ideologies, and links between social protections and production.25 Even when nations are confronted with common exogenous pressures (such as globalization), their particular regime's policy legacies influence new legislative reforms and perpetuate distinctive welfare state trajectories.26 Existing policies mold the construction of constituencies for new welfare state programs and create "policy ratchet" or "lock-in" effects that define solutions to new problems. Differences in the links between social protections and economic production embedded in the regimes have bearing on the programs' benefits to the social partners. Regimes have ideological legacies or interpretive effects: partly related to long-term patterns of party control, citizens over time come to expect certain things from their welfare states and from government.27 Thus, one finds mutations [End Page 47] in the programmatic realization of the ALMP concept that vary in accordance with these regime distinctions and that mirror the values, assumptions, deep logics, patterns of discourse, and institutional supports of each country's welfare regime.28 The new first- and second-order changes do not necessarily entail a rejection of the fundamental goals and values at the heart of the welfare state.29
The study of policy feedback effects on political behavior (found largely in the American politics subfield) suggests that social policy characteristics influence private sector actors' engagement with the state; policy characteristics have an impact on group formation because some societal actors are advantaged by the policies more than others.30 Programmatic characteristics, in addition to having resources effects (in distributing goods), also have interpretive effects (in conveying meaning about the policies to the general public). They influence the mass public's perceptions of viable policy alternatives. Consequently, prior policy choices tend to become locked in, both because changing the status quo has learning and coordination costs and because policies foster their own sets of norms and values.31 Furthermore, these characteristics have ripple effects in shaping constituents' broader views of government and their willingness to participate in democratic processes.32 Policy feedbacks also shape employers' preferences and, as this article seeks to demonstrate, managers' capacities to participate in implementation.33
Taking employers' involvement in implementation as a subset of political participation, I hypothesize that Danish and British firms' engagement [End Page 48] will be conditioned by policy effects from the current reforms and by legacies from past experiences with state programs. Regime-driven programmatic distinctions analogous to those perpetuating national regime trajectories in the legislative arena might influence the implementation processes through "policy feedback effects."34 To begin with, regimes construct target constituencies differently: social democratic programs are usually universally available, while liberal regimes are more likely to use means-tested eligibility standards. The social construction of target populations influences both the choice of policy tools and the arguments used to justify the policies; thus, policies that benefit "good" and "powerful" populations are more likely to appeal to the collective good than are those that benefit the "less deserving."35 While active social policies generally target the unemployed, we might expect Danish programs to be more universally available than British ones; consequently, Danish employers should view program recipients more favorably than should their British counterparts.
In addition, at the programmatic level, links between social protection and economic production may influence employers' calculations of the material costs and benefits of participation. Because social protections and economic production are coupled more tightly in coordinated market economies and Scandinavian welfare states than in liberal systems, Danish employers should anticipate greater material benefits from participation than should their British counterparts. Danish firms should participate in order to upgrade workers' skills while British firms should participate in order to obtain either cheap labor or public relations recognition. The preexisting literacy differential in the Danish and British workforces (22 percent of British citizens are in the bottom quintal in skills, yet only 10 percent of Danish workers fall into this category) enhance these differences in expectations about the programs' capacity to develop skills.36
Finally, regime differences in ideology may affect how employers assess the welfare state's efficacy and influence their willingness to participate. Over time, employers accept state social policies that they view as inevitable (especially under long-term, left party domination);37 [End Page 49] however, experience with the government agencies that administer the policies also shapes participants' attitudes toward the state, because the agencies represent a microcosm of government.38 These cumulative experiences form distinctive regime legacies and are observable in cross-national distinctions in beliefs about governmental capacities and legitimacy.
We can expect administrative legacies to enhance Danish firms' greater willingness (than their British peers) to participate in government programs because universal welfare states (such as those found in Scandinavia, where citizens feel that they are treated equally) generate higher levels of trust in government than do liberal regimes.39 In addition, Denmark has a tradition of strong local government dating back to at least the nineteenth century; Danish municipalities have long exerted enormous control over social programs and thus have provided citizens with a greater sense of self-determination.40 By contrast, the British party system theoretically allows the ruling party complete control over legislative initiatives; consequently, regime change often entails brave new initiatives that have little cross-partisan appeal, minimal societal input, and not much local control.41 Accordingly, while the Danish programs have been implemented with considerable local community input and initiative, the British New Deal has been seen very much as a national brainchild of the Blair administration. One might anticipate that a Danish local government official would feel ownership over an activation project in a manner not shared by her British counterpart. Thus, due to their past and current experiences in administering agencies, Danish firms should regard the administration of the plans more highly than should British firms.
Ideological differences over the scope and efficacy of government may also influence the strategies used by government actors to obtain employer participation. While social democratic regimes value norms of social solidarity, liberal regimes refer to market externalities to legitimate government interventions. Thus, we should expect the social democratic Danish state to make different types of appeals to employers than should the liberal British state. [End Page 50]
The institutional processes of business-government relations offer a third explanation for the differences in the take-up rates by Danish and British firms. Especially under conditions of bounded rationality, the institutional settings in which companies receive information and deliberate on political matters influence employers' perceptions of their social interests.42 It seems plausible that Danish firms' institutional traits may make them more likely to enlist than British firms, or that the institutional context of policy implementation differs across regimes.
These relevant institutional characteristics may pertain to internal company structures for processing public policy; for example, U.S. firms that have a government affairs office have been shown to be more supportive of government intervention than those that do not.43 While most European firms lack government affairs offices, the size of a professional human resources department may be an important determinant of employers' support for social programs.44 Alternatively, the relevant institutional characteristics may pertain to the external networks for firms; thus, a company's membership in an employers' association may largely determine its position on social policy. In either case, we might anticipate that the same institutional characteristics would shape firms' preferences in the two countries and that a greater number of Danish firms possess these characteristics.
It is also possible that the benefits of membership in an employers' association differ in the two countries, because corporatist employers' associations found in Denmark offer greater incentives for collective action toward shared social goals than pluralist British organizations. When employers are organized into corporatist groups, they may be more likely to favor social policies; corporatist organizations also increase the state's capacity to build support for and to secure compliance with its initiatives.45 Tripartite negotiations through the system of Danish corporatism have created a legacy of social partnership in overseeing labor-market programs (for insured workers); therefore, although firms have had no prior involvement with the social realm (for the uninsured), the corporatist channels might be replicated to bring them into [End Page 51]
![]() Click for larger view |
Table 2
Programmatic Details of the Danish and British Plans |
this new area.46 Thus, membership in a business association might be a significant determinant of preference in corporatist Denmark but not in pluralist Britain.
Programmatic Variations in Danish and British Social Policies
The Danish and British plans appear to be remarkably similar in the time limits they set on the receipt of passive benefits (six months for youth and one year for adults), in the recipients' compulsory participation, and in their outreach to firms.47 With ALMP, Denmark greatly reduced access to unemployment insurance, largely by imposing time limits and obligations to work. In his "fuzzy membership scores," Kvist moved Denmark from .98 in the accessibility of unemployment benefits in 1990 to a .53 ranking in 1998, similar to Britain's score of .52.48 Both countries asked firms to offer subsidized jobs and training. While training historically had been provided by the state in Denmark, active policies encouraged firm-based training; in Britain, training choices had been considered the responsibility of the individual since the rejection of more activist state measures in the 1970s, but the Blair reforms reassigned the government some responsibility for ensuring training.49 State subsidies paid to employers for hiring the unemployed have been similar—about 50 percent of wages in Denmark and 54 percent in Britain.50
Beyond these similarities, the Danish and British active labor-market and social plans diverge as anticipated (see Table 2). First, in keeping with social democratic values, the Danish plans serve a more universal constituency by offering jobs to the unemployed disabled for whom no rehabilitation is possible. With these protected jobs, the state has effectively developed subsidized minimum-wage employment that helps [End Page 53] firms hire for unproductive tasks within the company and retain disabled workers otherwise headed for early retirement.51 Alternatively, reflecting liberal regime assumptions, the British plans have served a more targeted population—long-term unemployed adults and youth—and have created only a small pilot program to address the needs of the disabled.
Second, the plans' benefits differ, especially in how much they contribute to skills development. Denmark spends more both on ALMP (1.58 percent of its 2000 GDP, compared with .37 percent of Britain's 2000 GDP) and on training for unemployed adults (.67 percent of its GDP, compared with Britain's .04 percent).52 The Danish plans for the long-term unemployed are closely linked to general state training programs for low-skilled workers; for example, job rotation schemes allow firms to use state subsidies to hire the long-term unemployed while their own employees receive skills training.53 By contrast, British programs, not surprisingly, have significantly less connection to skills development because public training resources have been limited since Thatcher's time and labor-market policy has been conceived of as a residual service for the unemployed.54
Third, the two countries, in keeping with their respective regime types, differ in their state ideological appeals to employers and plan administrators. Danish government policy entrepreneurs urged employers to satisfy their own long-term self-interests by working to advance collective economic and social interests; they linked a new economic formula for ending unemployment called the "encompassing labor market" (an economy that can be expanded to bring the socially excluded into its fold) to the collective social goal of ending social exclusion. The government also urged firms to identify unproductive tasks within the production process that people with subsidized protected jobs (available to individuals with reduced skills) could handle, and the state would then pay one-third to one-half of their wages. These new low-wage positions offered companies value by helping them with otherwise [End Page 54] difficult-to-complete tasks, reduced state spending (because the companies paid one-half to two-thirds of the wage), moved the long-term unemployed into the core economy (and thus reduced social exclusion), and maintained wage equality because the wages were subsidized by the state. Thus, the Danish experiment aimed to create more efficient social benefits, to revise social protections to meet the needs of the new economy, and to ameliorate long-term unemployment and social exclusion.55 British state officials used a very different ideology—the language of markets—to sell their programs and advocated "demand-led" strategies to tailor the programs to private-market needs. With this liberal welfare state strategy, firms were told that job seekers would be made "job ready," and personnel promised to tailor the skills of the potential workers to the needs of individual sectors.56
Danish and British bureaucrats used different mechanisms to mobilize employers to join the effort. The Danish Social Ministry decided not to spend resources on a big media campaign; instead, it reached out to bring firms into the social policy project with two diverse national strategies: expanding corporatist ties with the peak associations to the social arena and mobilizing firms directly with the creation of the "National Network of Firms." Initial efforts to involve the organizations in social policy deviated from the status quo, because government had responsibility over beneficiaries of social assistance. The subsequent outreach to individual firms marked an even greater deviation, because it was seen as undermining traditional corporatist channels. An industry respondent explained, "DA and DI didn't like the firms getting involved with the ministry; they were worried that there would be anarchy. Individual firms could give all sorts of opinions, with one firm saying one thing and another firm saying another. But the associations speak with one voice for all business."57
By contrast, the Blair administration did organize an expensive media campaign and held breakfast meetings at 10 Downing Street with CEOs of major firms to advertise the New Deal. It also created the New Deal Task Force to solicit employer input on program design and to encourage private voluntary participation. Although the administration made some overtures to the Confederation of British Industry and other groups, the business mobilization efforts largely worked outside of the formal employers' associations. As one high-ranking official at No. 10 put it, "We tried to work with business, but they just weren't organized." [End Page 55]
Denmark and Britain spend about the same on their public employment services (1.2-1.3 percent of GDP), but the two countries' bureaucrats created different types of administrative innovations to further their social projects.58 The Danes merged social and labor-market policy into a new employment ministry with control over both the insured workers (previously the domain of the old labor ministry) and the uninsured workers (previously the domain of the old social ministry). They have also constructed new institutions very much along the lines of labor-market policy for the socially excluded. A recently enacted law now requires each municipality to form a corporatist committee of representatives from business and labor to oversee social policy in the community. Dansk Arbejdgiversforening (DA) is responsible for selecting company participants to sit on these local social coordination committees. In addition, many municipalities have hired "firm consultants" to visit firms and identify potential protected jobs.
The British government reorganized the old job services and sought to raise confidence in the programs by transferring many tasks (especially those related to preparing New Dealers for work) to private intermediaries. A smaller pilot project, the Large Organizational Unit of the Employment Service, was developed to create account managers within the public sphere to handle vacancies within firms.
Policy Feedbacks on Employers' Views of Active Social Programs
Interviews with British and Danish employers confirm that differences in both programmatic design and patterns of implementation have had an impact on employers' willingness to participate. First, as anticipated, employers in the two countries perceived the program constituents quite differently. While 53 percent of the British firms declined to participate due to negative views of the unemployed, only 20 percent of the Danish companies offered this as a reason for nonparticipation (see Table 3).
Many Danish companies viewed the unemployed as a reasonable source of labor even though—as one manager explained—it might "take a bit longer to make sure that these workers can do OK." Negative views of the unemployed propelled some firms to participate, out of their irritation at seeing "people on unemployment sit around and smoke cigarettes and play the guitar." Yet 53 percent of British firms viewed the socially excluded as "unemployable," reporting that "most [End Page 56]
![]() Click for larger view |
Table 3
Employers' Responses to the Danish and British Plans |